期刊文献+

基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策中为自己-为所有人决策差异的眼动研究 被引量:2

When expectation-maximization-based theories work or do not work:An eye-tracking study of the discrepancy between everyone and every one
下载PDF
导出
摘要 主流的风险决策理论专家发展了一系列基于期望值最大化(expectation-maximization)的理论,以期捕获所有人的风险决策行为。然而大量证据表明,这些基于期望值最大化的理论并不能如同描述性理论那样理想地描述单一个体的决策行为。本研究采用眼动追踪技术,系统考察了个体在为所有人决策与为自己决策时的风险决策行为及信息加工过程的差异。本研究发现,基于期望值最大化的理论可捕获为所有人决策或为自己多次决策时的情况,却不能很好捕获个体为自己进行单次决策时的情况。本研究结果有助于理解基于期望值最大化的理论与启发式/非基于期望值最大化的理论的边界,为风险决策理论的划分和发展提供实证参考。 Mainstream theorists in risky decision-making have developed various expectation-maximization-based theories with the ambitious goal of capturing everyone’s choices.However,ample evidence has revealed that these theories could not capture every individual’s(“every one’s”)actual risky choice as descriptive theories.Substantial research has demonstrated that people do not follow the logical process suggested by expectation-maximization-based theories when making risky choices but rather rely on simplifying heuristics.From our perspective,the possible reason why mainstream decision theorists did not abandon the framework of expectation is that these theorists never doubted the validity of the expectation rule as a descriptive rule in describing decision-making under risk.We believe that expectation-maximization-based theories may capture risky choices when individuals make decisions for everyone.However,whether these theories could capture risky choices when individuals make decisions for themselves cannot be taken for granted.We thus used an eye-tracking technique to explore whether a theory for everyone would work well for every one.A total of 52 college students participated in the experiment.Three risky choice tasks were conducted in the present study:a D-everyone task,a D-multiple task,and a D-single task.In the D-everyone task,participants were asked to choose the more optimal option out of two options under the assumption that their selection would be the final decision for everyone who was facing the same choice—that is,everyone would be subject to the same choice but could receive different outcomes.In the D-multiple task,participants were asked to choose between the two options under the assumption that their selection would be applied a total of 100 times.In the D-single task,participants were asked to choose between the two options under the assumption that their selection would be applied only once to themselves.The participants’eye movements were recorded while they performed the tasks.Behavioral results revealed that,compared with the D-single task,participants selected more choices correctly predicted by EV and EU theories,and took a longer time to make a decision in the D-everyone and D-multiple tasks.Furthermore,eye movement measurements revealed the following.(1)The scanpath patterns of the D-everyone task and D-multiple task were similar but different from those of the D-single task.(2)The depth of information acquisition and the level of complexity of information processing in the D-everyone task and D-multiple task was higher than that in the D-single task.(3)The direction of information search in the D-everyone task and D-multiple task was more alternative-based than that in the D-single task.(4)The eye-tracking measures mediated the relationship between the task and the EV-consistent choice.In summary,behavioral and eye movement results supported our hypotheses that participants were likely to follow an expectation strategy in the D-everyone and D-multiple tasks,whereas they were likely to follow a heuristic/non-expectation strategy in the D-single task.We found that expectation-maximization-based theories could capture the choice of an individual when making decisions for everyone and for self in a multiple-play condition but could not capture the choice of an individual when making decisions for self in a single-play condition.The evidence for the discrepancy between everyone and every one,which was first reported in our study,implied that the possible reason why expectation-maximization-based theories do not work is that a default compatibility between the full set(everyone)and the subset(every one)does not exist.Our findings contribute to an improved understanding of the boundaries of expectation-maximization-based theories and those of heuristic/non-expectation models.Our findings may also shed light on the general issue of the classification of risky decision-making theories.
作者 刘洪志 李兴珊 李纾 饶俪琳 LIU Hong-Zhi;LI Xingshan;LI Shu;RAO Li-Lin(CAS Key Laboratory of Behavioral Science,Institute of Psychology,Chinese Academy of Sciences,Beijing 100101,China;University of Chinese Academy of Sciences,Beijing 100049,China;Department of Social Psychology,Zhou Enlai School of Government,Nankai University,Tianjin 300350,China;Department of Psychology and Behavioral Sciences,Zhejiang University,Hangzhou 310028,China)
出处 《心理学报》 CSSCI CSCD 北大核心 2022年第12期1517-1531,共15页 Acta Psychologica Sinica
基金 国家自然科学基金项目(71901126) 国家社会科学基金重大项目(19ZDA358) 教育部人文社会科学研究青年项目(19YJC190013) 中央高校基本科研业务费专项资金(63222045)资助。
关键词 风险决策 为所有人决策 期望值最大化 为自己–为所有人决策差异 眼动追踪技术 risky choice decision for everyone expectation-maximization discrepancy between everyone and every one eye-tracking
  • 相关文献

参考文献4

二级参考文献190

  • 1杨治良,钟毅平.现代实验心理学三种新方法评述[J].心理科学,1996,19(1):44-48. 被引量:13
  • 2李纾.艾勒悖论(Allais Paradox)另释[J].心理学报,2001,33(2):176-181. 被引量:17
  • 3孙悦,李纾.澳门人的风险知觉与赌博行为[J].心理学报,2005,37(2):260-267. 被引量:20
  • 4李纾.发展中的行为决策研究[J].心理科学进展,2006,14(4):490-496. 被引量:39
  • 5苏寅,李纾.(2010,10).从一次到多次,风险决策的眼动研究.第十三届全国心理学学术大会分组报告论文,上海.
  • 6孙红月,饶俪琳,周坤,李纾.(2009,11).最优应急预案:制定和实施的本质差异.第十二屠全国心理学学米大会分组报告论文,济南.
  • 7Aloysius, J. A. (2007). Decision making in the short and long run: Repeated gambles and rationality. British Journal of Mathematical and Statistical Psychology, 60(1), 61-69.
  • 8Arrow, K. J. (1982). Risk perception in psychology and economics. Economic Inquiry, 20(1), 1-9.
  • 9Asch, D. A., & Hershey, J. C. (1995). Why some health policies don't make sense at the bedside. Annals of Internal Medicine, 122, 846-850.
  • 10Barron, G., & Erev, I. (2003). Small feedback-based decisions and their limited correspondence to description-based decisions. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 16, 215-233.

共引文献63

同被引文献13

引证文献2

二级引证文献3

相关作者

内容加载中请稍等...

相关机构

内容加载中请稍等...

相关主题

内容加载中请稍等...

浏览历史

内容加载中请稍等...
;
使用帮助 返回顶部